登陆注册
9701500000059

第59章 《佃农理论》英语原著 (53)

The identification of crops which were dominantly intramarginal or dominantly marginal is not difficult. Between these extremes, however, there exist a number of crops which we are not able to identify, in terms of position, with the available information. In general, rice and common crops are intramarginal. "Common" crops are those which have been commonly grown under a free-market.[1] If we are to single out one of these as clearly intramarginal for our present discussion, rice is the obvious choice. Three reasons can be offered. First, most tenant farms had grown rice before the share restriction.[2] The high frequency of tenancy in paddy and upland rice fields is evident. Second, in Taiwan rice plantations could be single or double cropping, but it was physically impossible to rotate three crops of rice in one year over the same acre of land. This means that for rice crops the flexibility of adjustment through increasing the rate of planting was rather limited.[3] And third, rice crop yield, for upland rice in particular, is highly responsive to increasing the density of planting. With better fertilizers and irrigation, the yield per crop area might well double.[4]

Increasing Rice Crop Area

As is seen in table 3, using 1948 as the base year, the crop area of rice had increased 9.9 percent by 1951. The increase for paddy rice amounted to 9.5 percent, compared with a 16.5 percent increase for upland rice.[5] The reason for the difference is that, for paddy rice, double cropping had been more common before the share restriction, and the opportunity for adding additional crops was more limited.[6] For rice crops in general, the best growing season in Taiwan runs roughly from July to November.[7] For single cropping, there were more farmers choosing to plant the "second" (July to November) crop than the "first" (March to July), and thus the crop planted first or earlier in the calendar year should be the more frequent crop to add if a single-cropping farm now turned to double cropping. For paddy rice, however, we find that the first and second crops increased by the same percentage in crop area (9.5 percent and 9.4 percent). The reason is that the official counting of the first and second crop is based not on the date of planting but on the date of harvesting (before or after August 15).[8] For paddy rice, this dividing line cut off some of the earlier planted crops and counted them as "second." The same dividing line did not affect the counting of upland rice, for the first crop of upland rice was harvested earlier. Thus, for upland rice we find a 44 percent increase in crop area for the first crop, compared with only 3.9 percent increase for the second.[9]

Increasing Rice Yield per Crop Area

Whereas the increase in crop area as a result of increasing the rate of crop rotation is a discretionary variable determined in the market, the change in yield per crop hectare is dependent not only on the density of planting, but also on certain exogeneous variables such as weather and pests. Some judgment, however arbitrary, must be made as to whether a particular season is good, bad, or normal. For the period under study (1948-51), let me point out that in Taiwan there was no major agricultural disaster of any kind. That is, in the annual reports of agricultural losses due to drought, flood, and typhoon, we do not find notable annual differences.[10] Thus, the years under study may be regarded as "normal" —or equally "abnormal" —and nature was not a significant factor affecting crop yields.

Compared with 1948 (the base year), the rice yield per crop hectare was higher by 9.3 percent in 1949, 23.7 percent in 1950, and 26.4 percent in 1951.[11] The relatively small increase in 1949 might have been due to the fact that the enforcement of the share restriction began in April-June of that year. For 1949, we would expect the crop hectare yield for the second crop to increase by more than the first, since the share restriction was not enforced during the planting of some of the first crop. This is evident in upland rice, where for the first crop we find a 10 percent increase, as compared to a 41 percent increase for the second.[12] The increase in crop hectare yield was more significant percentagewise for upland rice than for paddy rice. The lower-grade soil quality of upland fields apparently allowed a greater margin of improvement through increasing the input density of planting. Of the 26.4 percent increase in 1951 over 1948, for example, paddy rice yield increased by 23.2 percent, compared with a 76.5 percent increase for upland rice.[13]

Conclusions

Taking rice as an intramarginal crop does not mean that the rate of planting (crop area) could not be increased. Extra rice crops were added, and the increase in crop area was greatest in the first crops of what had been single-cropping farms. The general increase in rice crop hectare yield was due to (a) the predominance of rice-growing in tenant farms and (b) the response of rice yield to the increase in the density of planting.

We measure the aggregate increase in annual rice yield as equal to the product of the index number of crop area multiplied by crop area yield. Using 1948 as the base year, we find a 13.7 percent increase in 1949, 33 percent in 1950 and 38.9 percent in 1951.[14] These percentages were increases in output from rice crops only. If we were able to separate rice outputs of tenant farms from those of owner farms, the increases might be greater for tenant farms than indicated.[15] At any rate, under the share restriction the landowners' rental incomes from land were partly restored by the increase in annual rice yield.

As is shown in table 3, the increases in crop area for rice and common crops are lower than for special crops and vegetables.

Among other common crops, we find that the increase in yield per crop area generally is less than for rice, and for a few common crops there is no increase.[16] But the more crucial test of the hypothesis of increased farming intensity lies not in rice and common crops, but in crops which were added at the margin.

同类推荐
  • 经济学越简单越实用

    经济学越简单越实用

    本书用通俗易懂的语言对经济学的本质、经济学独特的思考方式以及经济学的基本概念和规律进行了系统而深入浅出的讲解,并通过大量的生活案例,从日常生活、教育、职场、消费等方面,全面剖析了经济学在社会各个领域的广泛应用以及经济学规律对生活的巨大作用,帮助广大读者掌握经济学的精髓,学会用经济学的视角和思维观察、剖析种种生活现象,指导自己的行为,奠定成功人生的基础。
  • 国际经济学

    国际经济学

    国际经济学的研究对象包括微观的贸易理论与宏观的国际收支理论这两个基本的组成部分。微观部分主要介绍各种各样的贸易理论,包括作为古典贸易理论起源的重商主义贸易理论,古典贸易理论,新古典贸易理论,在第二次世界大战以后发展起来的各种新贸易理论,作为自由贸易理论之反论的贸易保护理论,以及有政府干预的战略性贸易理论等,对各种新贸易理论的评介是本教程的重点所在。宏观部分以开放经济条件下的国民收入流量核算体系为其分析的理论起点,然后依次从经常项目、资本项目以及货币因素的影响等角度介绍了多种有关国际收支调节的理论。
  • 源与流:西方文化中经济观念的演进

    源与流:西方文化中经济观念的演进

    本书是一项有关西方经济学前史的研究成果,从西方文化的角度来研究经济思想的发展历程。从古希伯来、古希腊、古罗马、基督教这些文化基因中去寻找“劳动”、“价值”、“看不见的手”、“交换”这些观念的历史根据,从地理大发现、文艺复兴、宗教改革、科学革命、哲学变革中去寻找经济科学兴起的前提与方法。从古希伯来人的宗教典籍到近代早期的重农学派,比较完整地勾勒出亚当·斯密以前西方文化和经济观念交织生成的思想风貌。
  • 我是理财小专家

    我是理财小专家

    本书是《阳光少年》系列丛书之一,本书介绍了节俭习惯如何养成,压岁钱怎么花,如何为自己的未来投资,什么是信用卡等基本理财知识,通过一个个生动的故事向小读者们介绍正确的财富观念和理财方式,使其会懂得珍惜父母辛苦挣来的钱,养成勤俭节约、科学消费的好习惯。
  • 粤商经营之道

    粤商经营之道

    全书主要由六部分内容构成。第一部分探讨了多元化与专业化的战略选择在粤商发展中的作用,第二部分是一些基本的多元化理论知识介绍,第三部分探讨粤商进行多元化或者专业化战略选择的动因,第四部分分析多元化或专业化战略是否有助于粤商更好地利用信息优势,第五部分探讨政府对企业的干预等,第六部分是全文总结,并提出一些相关的政策建议。
热门推荐
  • 天行

    天行

    号称“北辰骑神”的天才玩家以自创的“牧马冲锋流”战术击败了国服第一弓手北冥雪,被誉为天纵战榜第一骑士的他,却受到小人排挤,最终离开了效力已久的银狐俱乐部。是沉沦,还是再次崛起?恰逢其时,月恒集团第四款游戏“天行”正式上线,虚拟世界再起风云!
  • 妃常蛊怪之女侯请上座

    妃常蛊怪之女侯请上座

    一朝重生,成为宣启国女侯爷?然而并没有想象中的锦衣玉食,没有万人簇拥,更没有光芒万丈,有的只是众人的不屑与鄙视。女子为官,是为有违常理;傻子为官,是为有违忠义?呵呵……去他的!傻子?如果她是傻子,那被傻子玩弄于掌中的是什么东西?初来乍到,迎接她的是面临受封礼却无官服的窘境,还有一群等着看热闹的人。呵……姐姐我连小时候尿床都没有,还会让你们这帮无名小卒看笑话,那才是个笑话!她倒是想看看,究竟是谁被看笑话?锋芒初绽,却引来更多嫉恨与危机。但且看她如何在异世步步为营,胜者为王!
  • 傲娇傅爷超护短

    傲娇傅爷超护短

    众人眼中,季云歌是个不折不扣的狐狸精。不仅抢了自己姐姐的未婚夫,还一点羞耻感都没有。傅斯城:“你们懂个屁!我跟歌儿本来就是绝配。”众人眼中,傅斯城矜贵无双风度翩翩。妥妥的北川第一金龟婿。季云歌:“你们眼都瞎,那就是个臭不要脸的幼稚鬼!”一直以来,季云歌都觉得傅斯城不过是想睡她。却不知,他想要的,不光是她的人,还有她的心。......世人都说季云歌是狐狸精,但她这辈子只对一个人用过心,那就是傅斯城。世人都说傅斯城冷性冷情,他却把一颗火热的心捧到她的面前,那人是季云歌。
  • 上门女婿

    上门女婿

    欺他,辱他,视他为蝼蚁的岳父岳母小姨子,在得知他的真实身份后,全都跪了……“好女婿,求求你,别离开我女儿行不行?”
  • 盛唐悲歌

    盛唐悲歌

    在浩瀚的历史长河当中,盛世大唐一直是让无数人魂牵梦绕的。这是一个英雄豪杰辈出的时代,也是文学大家井喷的黄金时期。多少后来人都怀揣梦回大唐的憧憬,想去感受一下盛世大唐的绚丽多彩。唐玄宗李隆基作为唐代历史上地位和影响力,唯一能和唐太宗李世民相媲美的一代英主。他不仅一手缔造了开元盛世的繁荣,而且他与杨贵妃的缠绵悱恻的爱情故事更是至今被世人所津津乐道。开元年间的繁荣,歌舞升平的盛世的景象让唐玄宗有些目眩神迷。耳边歌功颂德的声音也让唐玄宗彻底迷失了自己。改国号为天宝以后一些列昏庸的举措,更是直接导致了盛唐的由繁盛到衰落。盛世大唐从唐玄宗的开元之治达到顶峰,又因安史之乱的影响变得一蹶不振,衰败萧条。
  • 蛮荒皇者

    蛮荒皇者

    远古时代,蛮荒大陆,万族林立,人族先天不足,受万族奴役、欺压,毫无尊严可言,直到有一天,一个人族奋力反抗,他始创修炼之法,剥夺妖族造化为己用,强大己身,教化人族,带领人族崛起…把人族从苦难中解救出来,百万年以后,一个出身微末的少年,同样拥有一颗强者之心,继续带领人族崛起,成为万族共主…
  • 天行

    天行

    号称“北辰骑神”的天才玩家以自创的“牧马冲锋流”战术击败了国服第一弓手北冥雪,被誉为天纵战榜第一骑士的他,却受到小人排挤,最终离开了效力已久的银狐俱乐部。是沉沦,还是再次崛起?恰逢其时,月恒集团第四款游戏“天行”正式上线,虚拟世界再起风云!
  • 江游记

    江游记

    混沌的开辟,洪荒的灭世,无数的文明,种族的战火,混沌的至宝,开启轮回的无上神,神与魔,远古的文明和修真文明的碰撞,摩擦的火花,尽在江游记
  • 时宜不如你

    时宜不如你

    萧晓没想到这一切来得这么突然,事情源于她研究生考试结束后的一个星期,关于她的工作问题,她第一次和父母起了明面上的争执,一场眼泪的洗礼之后,她决定曲线救国,先挣钱,待时宜。但是这个男人是怎么回事?奶茶店的偶遇,她班上学生的家长么,又成了她相亲的对象,相亲结束后又要一直出现在她身边……这样真的好么,好烦哦,再这样下去,她可能真的会去表白的,所以……她最后等到的到底是什么呢
  • 迷途人与他的萤火虫们

    迷途人与他的萤火虫们

    J,为了实现他心中那个遥远的目的而开始从事杀手工作。手刃了无数条生命的他已经开始麻木了,直到有一天,一个曾经被他杀死过的女孩出现在他的面前,于是J的生活开始发生巨变。