登陆注册
9701500000047

第47章 《佃农理论》英语原著 (41)

It follows that to maximize his income from land subject to the legal constraint of rental share reduction, (a) the owner can successfully induce the tenant to commit more farming inputs as long as the tenant receives a farming income greater than his alternative earning (since other potential tenants will offer to do so); and (b) provided that condition (a) holds, the landowner will induce more intensive farming as long as the marginal return to additional tenant inputs is greater than zero, for the rental income under the share constraint will then be higher than without additional tenant inputs. In condition (a), we have the non-land cost constraint; in (b), we have the limit of the physical constraint, namely, zero marginal returns for tenant inputs. The maximization of rental income for the landowner will be subject to whichever limit comes first. The result will be an increase in farming intensity, simply defined here as an increase in f/h, the amount of nonland farming inputs (or nonland farming cost, f) per land area. The economic implications of this are important, and we shall analyze them at some length.

But first certain assumptions must be specified. (1) After the imposition of

, assume that there is no compensating (offsetting) payment of any kind. In other words, the owner's income from land is confined strictly to

of the annual yield. (2) For analytical convenience, assume that all farming costs other than land are financed by the tenant. The relaxation of this assumption will not affect the implied allocation. And (3), assume zero transaction costs.

A.Partial Land Repossession —Illustrated with Input Adjustments for One Tenant Farm

The increase of farming intensity under the share constraint may be attained in two general ways. One is to hold the tenant inputs constant, while competition allows the landowner to reduce tenant landholding through partial repossession of land. Another way is to keep the tenant landholding unchanged, while competition induces more tenant inputs over the given land, which is also to the interest of the landowner. of course, the landowner may choose a combination of both. In any event, the result is an increase in tenant inputs on land in tenant farms. The first is discussed in this section; the second is discussed in section B. Both are different views of the same phenomenon.

Figure 6 involves manipulations of figure 3 in chapter 2. A brief review of its notations is in order. The curve f/h is a rectangular hyperbola, representing the contractually stipulated (fixed) cost of tenant inputs, f, divided by the landholding, h. Given the average product of land,

associated with the constant tenant inputs, the rent per unit of land, (q-f)/h, is defined. The initial tenant landholding is oa, where (q-f)/h is at a maximum, and the open market rental percentage equals ar/ap.

Under the additional constraint of

, however, the (q-f)/h curve is no longer relevant for decision making. Instead of maximizing rent per acre of land, (q-f)/h, the owner will now maximize (q/h)

subject to the constraint of f/h. To illustrate, suppose the initial rental percentage of 70 percent (ar/ap) is legally reduced to

of 40 percent. The landowner's share constraint is thus represented by the curve

, which is at 40 percent of the average product of land. This will be the case as long as the rent is reduced and stated according to percentage, regardless of whether the initial contract is for fixed or share rent.[1] The corresponding share for the tenant will be

.

Without resource reallocation, the rent per unit of land will now be ae instead of ar, and the tenant's income will be at times oa, which is higher than his alternative earning. To maximize (q/h)

, the landowner can reduce the tenant's landholding to ob without reducing tenant inputs, subject to the nonland cost constraint, f/h. Given f/h as shown, competitive equilibrium is reached at point h, where the tenant income from farming equals the tenant (nonland) cost. The rent per unit of land for the landowner will now be bg, which is higher than ae. To utilize the withdrawn land, the landowner can parcel it to other tenants in a similar manner, cultivate it himself, or hire laborers to till it (this last possibility was restricted in Taiwan). The result, under the strictly enforced share constraint, is a resource reallocation to a higher f/h ratio in tenant farms, or an increase in tenant farming intensity over that in an unrestrained market.

The economic implications of increasing f/h are several. Let us assume that there are only two factors of production, land, h, and tenant labor, t. Under this assumption, total nonland farming cost, f, is the prevailing wage, W, times t. Thus, given W, an increase in f/h means an increase in t/h. At the initial land size division T1, the marginal product of land,

, is ar. With the higher t/h ratio associated with landholding ob after the adjustment, the marginal product of land becomes higher. This means that the marginal product of land would be higher in adjusted tenant farms than in owner farms. On the other hand, the marginal product of tenant input will be lower than in other occupations. In other words, the marginal cost of tenant input is higher than its marginal product. Thus, nonland inputs invested in tenant farms as a result of the share restriction will yield returns at a rate less than the interst rate.

Two side remarks can be made. First, if the tenant wage rate is low enough to form f*/h (dotted line in fig. 6), and given the constraints and assumptions specified, competitive equilibrium becomes undefined. In this case, the landowner will reduce land size to oc, where (q/h)

is at a maximum and where the marginal product of tenant labor (the "other" factor) will be zero.[2] The tenant will then be receiving a residual income (which equals ij times oc), an amount which the landowner could extract in a lump sum (a compensating payment which we assume away).

同类推荐
  • 探索与发展

    探索与发展

    本论文集由109篇获奖论文集结而成,包括《如何加强事业单位对外投资监管》、《行政事业资产管理存在的问题集对策》、《进一步加强行政事业资产处置管理的思考》、《有效利用资产管理信息系统加强资产管理》等。
  • 中国经济:战略、调控与改革

    中国经济:战略、调控与改革

    本书由国家发展和改革委员会经济研究所2006-2007年度基本科研专项资金课题优秀成果编辑而成。
  • 我们向何处去

    我们向何处去

    本书从两部类模型出发,创新地发展了马克思主义经济学对债务危机进行“破局”,为人们观察、了解世界债务提供了一个全新的视角,为“中国模式”注入了新的内容,对世界经济形势进行了前瞻性的思考。从文化、历史、宗教、经济、政治、军事、地缘等方面展现了精彩纷呈的世界“大棋局”。
  • 动物界经济学

    动物界经济学

    从动物身上可以找到自己的本源,从经济学上找到指导我们的哲理。将五彩缤纷的动物世界与富含生活智慧的经济学原理相结合,并对人类的社会现状做系统分析,会让我们对自己正在面临的或即将面临的难题找到有效的解决方式。
  • 金色的诞辰——武威区域经济实证分析

    金色的诞辰——武威区域经济实证分析

    本书内容有文化是明天的经济、民勤湖区的贫困问题怎样解决、走符合武威实际的可持续发展之路、如何启动运用好民间资金、着力把草畜产业培育成支柱产业等。
热门推荐
  • 睡仙

    睡仙

    茫茫大地,朗朗乾坤,万千世界。唯有修仙成大道,逆转天地,成道果。风云变际,斗转星移,仙魔终有一战,待到那时,破开虚空,飞身上界。
  • 天行

    天行

    号称“北辰骑神”的天才玩家以自创的“牧马冲锋流”战术击败了国服第一弓手北冥雪,被誉为天纵战榜第一骑士的他,却受到小人排挤,最终离开了效力已久的银狐俱乐部。是沉沦,还是再次崛起?恰逢其时,月恒集团第四款游戏“天行”正式上线,虚拟世界再起风云!
  • 重生异界成熊

    重生异界成熊

    一觉醒来成了熊,还是so可爱的小熊,重生成小熊就算了,可我怎么被美女姐姐抱着?等等,这位姐姐好眼熟,这,这不是我梦里的哪位神仙姐姐嘛。“小家伙,让我看看你是男孩还是女孩。”魂淡,这位姐姐不是神仙姐姐,而是色姐姐……
  • 天行

    天行

    号称“北辰骑神”的天才玩家以自创的“牧马冲锋流”战术击败了国服第一弓手北冥雪,被誉为天纵战榜第一骑士的他,却受到小人排挤,最终离开了效力已久的银狐俱乐部。是沉沦,还是再次崛起?恰逢其时,月恒集团第四款游戏“天行”正式上线,虚拟世界再起风云!
  • 快穿之拯救她

    快穿之拯救她

    女主落安安,和孔雀小八帮助原主实现愿望,穿梭一个又一个世界,从毕业走向人生巅峰
  • 旅商诸天

    旅商诸天

    世间本无恶,可现在有了。时间长河被染红。无尽混沌中无数生灵死亡,那一抹血色染红了诸天。我听到了生灵在哀嚎,我听到万物在求饶,我听到了世人在悲泣,是我错了吗?
  • 重生之贵女本荣华

    重生之贵女本荣华

    ——主要讲述蜕变后的女主回到侯府后,凭借自己的聪明才智,一步步化解各种危机,将高冷傲娇男主调教成忠犬的故事。(虐渣宅斗+重生穿越+夺舍爽文)***她本尊贵,奈何遭人逆天改命。幸得上天垂怜,获得新生,大难不死重回侯府,却不想侯门一入深似海。前有庶姐的针锋相对和继妹的鬼蜮伎俩,后有继母的居心叵测,后宅各种阴私腌臜事儿接二连三。更可恨的是,她的杀亲仇人过着锦衣玉食的生活,霸占她的亲情,夺她的初恋,抢她的夫君。她立誓要以血还血,虐仇人,治恶人,拖敌后腿护至亲,还要活出属于自己的荣华锦绣人生!他出身尊贵,霞姿月韵,才华出众,乃是戌朝赫赫有名的战神,在众贵女千金们眼中,是神一般的存在,却偏偏对上曾被他唾弃的她,从此被她一步步感化,踏上宠妻忠犬之路。……姑娘:可否让小女子搭个顺风车?公子:抱歉,男女授受不亲。……公子:你真想嫁给本公子?姑娘:不是你想娶本姑娘吗?……某位公子忍不住相思之苦,夜潜某姑娘的闺阁,想一亲芳泽。——流氓!某姑娘一拳挥过去。——我是你相公,不对你流氓想我对谁流氓!PS:1、此文1V1,双洁,结局HE2、言情为主,宅斗为辅3、背景架空,谢绝考究!
  • 一代狐后

    一代狐后

    她是亡国公主,被迫与诺风国人王子诺联姻,秘密将收集的情报交予华池国。群臣皆说她是狐后,魅惑君主,祸乱朝纲。但人王子诺偏偏独宠她一人,为她遣散后宫。数年后,华池国的铁骑踏平了诺风国的万里江山。抱着子诺僵硬的尸体,她留下两行清泪,道:“别怕,我在…”说完自尽在子诺身旁。
  • 狼族王子的纯情公主

    狼族王子的纯情公主

    拥有绝美的外貌的她,身为血族公主,竟然被敌族陷害,失去了两百年前的记忆!两百年前的一幕幕血腥画面,她最最信任的人都背叛了她!她的哥哥在她深陷困难处境的时候悠然自若!连她最最亲爱的母亲大人也没有一丝一毫要帮助她的意思!就这样,她陷进深渊!两百年后,她又遇到了他们,他们不认识她了,但是他们还记得她给他们带来的感觉。她已经忘记了两百年前的事,被敌族收留的她又恢复了记忆。回到血族,她还会是以前人人都凌辱的废物公主吗?
  • 为夫要举高高

    为夫要举高高

    全天府国谁人不知,薛丞相有独女,名唤薛依依,被宠成”女魔王“,全天府国谁人不晓,大年三十那夜,薛依依冲撞了圣兽遭了报应,昏睡了三天三夜,醒后胡言乱语着了魔,还成天花楼里跑,惹得议论纷纷。撒糖1:某女一路逃亡至青楼,两眼汪汪抱住某人大腿:你要救我!某人语气决绝:你不是要成亲了吗?还来这里做什么?某女鼻涕往某人裤腿上狠狠一擦,恢复本来面目:“废话少说,你救不救!”某人脸一黑:不救!……“你不救,那你就等着我将你的男……”突然一根玉指落在了张牙舞爪的某女子唇上。“嘘……别动!”玉指的主人一个翻转,吐气若幽兰。某女口水一咽,乖的像只兔子。撒糖2:某人痛彻心扉的趴在某女的床边:只要你能醒过来,你要我怎样都愿意……某女笑着睁开眼,虚弱着还不忘要戏弄某人,开玩笑的说:现在我醒了,那你对我卖个萌怎么样?不过某女也只是想想而已,谁料……一向高傲的某人傻愣愣模仿道:娘子,为夫要亲亲抱抱举高高……某女幸福的嗤笑出声……